he Decline of the Middle Class
and the Fall of the Roman Republic
Carlos Felipe Amunátegui Perelló
Université pontiicale catholique du Chili *
1. Introduction
Citizen’s acceptance is one of the basic elements for governance in any
political system. In fact, all political systems need the collaboration of the governed,
although those which are perceived as illegitimate will require a larger proportion
of coercion from the State apparatus to function. Anyhow, all political systems
alternate the use of force with the voluntary compliance of the governed to fulil
their goals. he proportion of violence that a system requires increases when its
results are perceived as unfair, and decreases when citizens are participants of its
successes. he wider the perception of unfairness, the larger the proportion the
elite will have to invest in coercion to sustain the political order and, therefore, the
system will have a smaller ability to expand and develop. In North’s words: “he
costs of maintenance of an existing order are inversely related to the perceived
legitimacy of the existing system” 1.
In participatory political systems, as modern democracy, citizen’s acceptance
is fundamental, for their active involvement is required for the system to work,
even at the most basic level in order to convince them to go to the polls every
number of years. It is not a coincidence that democracy only acquired stability in
continental Europe ater the world wars, which unleashed one of the most massive
processes of economic equalization known to humankind 2. he wealth of old elites
simply vanished through inlation — caused by the abandon of gold standard —,
physical destruction of capital and the stock shocks of the Great Depression.
* Professor of Roman Law of the Pontiicia Universidad Católica de Chile, Facultad de Derecho,
piso 4º, Alameda 340, Santiago de Chile; camunate@uc.cl. his work was supported by Conicyt
by grant Fondecyt Regular 1141231 and Anillos de Investigación Asociativa project SOC 1111.
1. D.C. North, Structure and Change in Economic History, New York 1981, p. 53.
2. Piketty, on the matter gives some interesting data on wealth distribution in England and France
during the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. he most striking feature is the enormous
equalization process that took place ater the two World Wars and the Great Depression. See:
T. Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, 2014, pp. 126–139.
Revue Internationale des Droits de l’Antiquité 56 (2014)
Amunategui.indd 5 05-07-15 15:32:15
6 Carlos Felipe Amunátegui Perelló
his brutal equalization brought the decline of inheritance as the main source of
wealth 3, compared to the new possibilities that were open for the common man if
he had access to education. he collapse of wealth concentration during the wars,
brought a new social system that was perceived as egalitarian, where education and
hard work were considered as the foundations of wealth. his is the substrate that
has stabilized the political regimes of Western European societies, avoiding the
emergence of totalitarian political regimes that could jeopardize their development.
In contrast, Latin American societies, were no such collapse happened, have being
periodically afected by totalitarian tendencies.
Anyhow, during the last thirty years, wealth accumulation has been rapidly
increasing in Europe and the United States 4 and, consequently, a long list of
populist organizations have being emerging from the bowels of their political
systems, as the Tea Party or the Front National, and other political movements
of doubtful democratic credentials. Evidently, we cannot know if these political
groups are the outpost or an authoritarian drit in the self proclaimed “advanced
democracies”, but if the wealth concentration process deepens, this is perfectly
possible. his work is a comparative exercise that will take the case of a diferent
society, the Roman republic, where wealth accumulation brought the decline of a
participatory political regime, which was inally replaced by the Empire.
2. Wealth Concentration and Middle Class in Republican Rome
Before treating the governance problems that afected Antiquity, it is
important to consider some key points regarding the creation and distribution of
wealth that afect all pre-industrial societies. Firstly, it should be taken into account
that in such societies economic growth is negligible and, therefore, any increase in
population will necessarily imply a new provision of dispossessed whose survival
is uncertain 5. Antiquity is a Malthusian world, where increases in productivity
accomplished by technical innovation are soon absorbed by population increases
that lead to new social crisis 6. In such conditions, the most efective way to increase
the GDP is to expand the mass of ixed capital through military conquest of the
3. T. Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, 2014, p. 377.
4. J. Stiglitz, he Price of Inequality. How today’s divided society endangers our future. New York
and London 2013, p. 1–27.
5. W.V. Harris, ‘Poverty and Destitution in the Roman Empire’, in Rome’s Imperial Economy,
Twelve Essays. Oxford and New York, Kindle Ed. 2011, l. 349.
6. On economic growth in Antiquity, the debate seems nowadays to be centred on the speed in
which population growth can absorb the positive efects of economic growth (W. Scheidel,
‘Physical well-being’, in W. Scheidel [ed.], he Cambridge Companion to he Roman Economy,
Cambridge 2012, pp. 321–333; R. Saller, ‘Framing the Debate over Growth in the Ancient
Economy’, in W. Scheidel and S. Von Reden [eds.], he Ancient Economy, New York 2010,
pp. 251–269; P. Temin, he Roman Market Economy, New Jersey 2013, pp. 195–239).
Amunategui.indd 6 05-07-15 15:32:15
he Decline of the Middle Class and the Fall of the Roman Republic 7
neighbouring territories 7. his is the cause for war’s central role in Antiquity, for
it meant something equivalent to economic growth. Antiquity’s military obsession
was especially important for societies that had to deal with demographic growth
or that held political systems that were involved in the efective amelioration of life
conditions for the governed. hat is why democracies in Antiquity were invariably
imperialistic, while aristocracies not necessarily.
Another element to consider is that Antiquity’s economic structure was not
favourable for paid work. Although is existed 8, its economic role was marginal,
especially for the ubiquitous presence of slavery 9, as for other strategies to obtain
subordinate labour typical of earlier Antiquity 10. Diferently to Modern world 11,
distribution of wealth and capital were equivalent. he irrelevance of economic
growth and the dependence of income to capital implied that any governance crisis
might quickly translate into propositions of agrarian reform, especially regarding
newly conquered land.
3. Land Distribution and the Licinan-Sextian Laws
Following Roman historians, the eve of the Republic was rather shaky in social
terms. Tradition reports a long struggle between two social groups, the Patricians
and the Plebeians, whose origins are not clear 12. his conlict would have developed
7. In Morley’s words: “the importance of violence as a mode of accumulation and a cultural
practice in antiquity can scarcely be exaggerated” (N. Morley, Trade in Classical Antiquity,
Cambridge, Kindle Ed. 2007, l. 505).
8. Recently the role of paid labour in Antiquity is under re-examination. he possibility of a real
labour market has being put forward (W.V. Harris, ‘Poverty and Destitution in the Roman
Empire’, in Rome’s Imperial Economy, Twelve Essays. Oxford and New York, Kindle Ed. 2011,
l. 546–578; D. Kehoe, ‘Contract labor’ in W. Scheidel [ed.] Roman Economy, New York 2012,
pp. 114–131). he most extreme position on the matter points to the existence of a large labour
market fully operative during the Early Empire (P. Temin, he Roman Market Economy, New
Jersey 2013, pp. 114–138).
9. Slavery seems to have being introduced during Etruscan monarchy, although we cannot
be certain of it (G. Franciosi, ‘Res mancipi e res nec mancipi’, Labeo 5–3 [1959], p. 375;
G. Franciosi, Famiglia e persone in Roma antica, Turin 1992, p. 206; F. De Martino, ‘Clienti
e condizioni materiali in Roma arcaica’, in Diritto economia e società nel mondo romano,
Naples 1997, pp. 82–83; F. De Martino, ‘Intorno all’origine della schiavitù a Roma’, in Diritto
economía e società nel mondo romano, Naples 1997, pp. 27–57).
10. Among them, we should mention the clientela, with its connected obligation of lending personal
service to the patronus, nexum, a loan guaranteed with the physical person of the debtor, and
the transfer of sons and daughters through mancipium.
11. In modern world the distribution of income and capital are diferent. Generally speaking,
capital tends to be much more concentrated than income, for the latter includes paid work. See:
T. Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century, Cambridge 2014, p. 39–71.
12. he theories about the origins of Patricians and Plebeians are discouragingly many. Some are
based on a dualist hypothesis where there would be either an ethnical diference between them
(V. Arangio-Ruiz, Storia del diritto romano. Naples 2006, p. 21), or at least regarding their
Revue Internationale des Droits de l’Antiquité 56 (2014)
Amunategui.indd 7 05-07-15 15:32:15
8 Carlos Felipe Amunátegui Perelló
for three key elements: legal knowledge, access to political power and the control
of public land. Although academic debate has literally being going on for centuries,
we will only partially face the problem of land and its distribution as an element of
our analysis.
Some scholars believe that the whole conlict is a mere invention of the
annalistic tradition, a kind of pseudo-historic anticipation of the real conlict
for land control that took place during the 2nd century BC 13. Anyhow, there are
enough elements in the tradition to discard this thesis partially or completely,
citizenship (A. Guarino, Le origine quiritarie. Raccolta di Scritti romanistici, Naples 1973,
pp. 9–17). Others believe that the Patrician and Plebeian groups formed gradually during the
Monarchy, either by the fulilment of priestly duties (R.E. Mitchell, ‘he Deinition of patres
and plebs: An End to the Struggle of the Orders’, in K.A. Raaflaub [ed.], Social Struggles
in Archaic Rome. New Prespectives on the Conlict of the Orders, Oxford 2005, pp. 128–167),
by a process of wealth accumulation connected with the exercise of power in the Senate
(L. Harmand, Société et économie de la république romaine, Paris 1976, p. 32; A. Drummond,
‘Rome in the Fith Century II: he Citizen Community’, in F.W. Walbank, A.E. Astin,
M.W. Frederiksen and R.M. Ogilvie [eds.], he Cambridge Ancient History, VII, p. 2,
Cambridge 1989, pp. 172–242; A. Momigliano, ‘he Origins of Rome’, in F.W. Walbank,
A.E. Astin, M.W. Frederiksen and R.M. Ogilvie [eds.], he Cambridge Ancient History, VII,
p. 2, Cambridge 1989, pp. 52–112 and A. Momigliano, ‘he Rise of the plebs in the Archaic
Age of Rome’, in K.A. Raaflaub [ed.], Social Struggles in Archaic Rome. New Prespectives
on the Conlict of the Orders, Oxford 2005, pp. 168–184; A. Magdelain, ‘De L’auctoritas
patrum à l’auctoritas senatus’, in Jus imperium auctoritas. Études de droit romain, Paris 1990,
pp. 385–403; T.J. Cornell, he Beginnings of Rome and Italy from the Bronze Age to the Punic
Wars (c. 1000–264 BC), London and New York 1995, pp. 244–258; K.A. Raaflaub, ‘From
Protection and Defense to Ofense and Participation: Stages in the Conlict of the Orders’, in
K.A. Raaflaub [ed.], Social Struggles in Archaic Rome. New Prespectives on the Conlict of the
Orders, Oxford 2005, pp. 185–222; G. Forsythe, A Critical History of Early Rome, Berkeley
and Los Angeles 2006, p. 162; C.J. Smith he Roman Clan. he gens from Ancient Ideology
to Modern Anthropology, Cambridge 2006, p. 305), or through the immigration of cratsmen
of a predominantly urban environment (Plebeians), confronted to an agrarian aristocracy
(J.-C. Richard, ‘Rélexions sur les “origines” de la plebe’, in Bilancio critico su Roma arcaica fra
monarchia e repubblica, Rome 1993, pp. 27–41 and J.-C. Richard, ‘Patricians and Plebeians:
he Origin of a Social Dichotomy’, in K.A. Raaflaub [ed.] Social Struggles in Archaic Rome.
New Prespectives on the Conlict of the Orders, Oxford 2005, p. 107–127), which eventually closed
its ranks at the beginnings of the Republic. What we believe most likely, is that the Patricians
were the members of the old gentilician clans, while the Plebs were outsiders (F. De Martino,
‘La gens, lo stato e le classi in Roma antica’, in Diritto economía e società nel mondo romano,
Naples 1997, pp. 25–49 and F. De Martino, Storia costituzionale romana, Naples 1973, p. 78;
P. Bonfante, ‘La gens e la familia’, in Scritti Guiridici, Famiglia e successione, Turin 1916,
pp. 1–17 and P. Bonfante, ‘Teorie vecchie e nuove sulle formazione sociali primitive’, in Scritti
Guiridici, Famiglia e successione, Turin 1916, pp. 18–63; C. Castello, Studi suldiritto familiar e
gentilizio romano, Rome 1972 [=1942], p. 49; L. Capogrossi Colognesi, Diritto e potere nella
storia di Roma, Naples 2007, pp. 49–51).
13. R. Maschke, Zur heorie und Geschichte der römischen Agrargesetze, Naples 1980 [=1906],
p. 14; E. Gabba, ‘Motivazioni economiche nell’opposizione alla lege agraria di Tib. Sempronio
Graccho’, in J.A.S. Evans (ed.), Polis and Imperium: Studies in Honour of Edward Togo Salmon,
Toronto 1974, p. 135.
Amunategui.indd 8 05-07-15 15:32:15
he Decline of the Middle Class and the Fall of the Roman Republic 9
and to conirm the existence of a conlict over land control between these groups
during the Early Republic 14.
Apparently the Plebeian group did not have access to the newly conquered
lands, which remained as public lands (ager publicum), theoretically open to the
use of any citizen 15. We do not know the exact reason for this exclusion, but in
practice, it seems only the Patricians had access to them 16 and they were the only
ones that efectively occupied them. he struggle of the orders had at its core the
Plebeian demand for land distribution. he disruptive efects of agrarian reform
laws are classically expressed in Livy’s comment on the major public disorders
caused by them 17.
Anyhow, the conlict inally lowered its intensity only ater 367 BC, ater some
140 years of permanent hostility, with the leges Liciniae-Sextiae. hese statutes,
among other major reforms, limited the maximal amount of public land that any
individual could occupy. From this moment onwards, each military victory was
accompanied by a land distribution of the conquered territory, whether in the
14. F. Serrao, ‘Lotte per la terra e per la casa a Roma’, in F. Serrao (ed.), Legge e società nella
repubblica romana, Naples, p. 67; A. Drummond, ‘Rome in the Fith Century II: he Citizen
Community’, in F.W. Walbank, A.E. Astin, M.W. Frederiksen and R.M. Ogilvie (eds.),
he Cambridge Ancient History, VII, p. 2, Cambridge 1989, p. 237; S.T. Roselaar, Public Land
in the Roman Republic. A Social and Economic History of Ager Publicus in Italy, 396–89 BC.
Oxford and New York 2010, p. 28.
15. Sic. Fl. De condic. agr. 101.9–13 and 102.9–13.
16. he Patrician control of public land is quite straight forward in the tradition. Nonnius reports
that the Plebeians were excluded of the public land just because they were Plebeians (Non.
149M.17: Quicumque propter plebitatem agro publico eiecti sunt). Although the reasons for this
exclusion are unknown to us, we could theorize that their exclusion from the gentes, the original
clans that composed the city, might lay behind it. Another possibility is that they simply lacked
the social power to impose their control over public lands and that more powerful people (the the
rich Patrician) could simply expel them by violence. Anyhow, during the monarchy, tradition
reports many land distributions made by the kings to favour the poor (Dion Hal. 2.62.2–3;
3.1.4–5; 2.29.6; 3.31.3; 3.9.8; 4.10.3; 4.13.1), but during the early Republic these distributions
cease abruptly. By that time, the conquered land usually remains as ager publicus, save from
some rather exceptional cases in which colonies were established (Liv. 2.21.6; 2.31.4; 2.34.6;
3.1.5–6). he irst massive land distribution during the Republic is not of agricultural land, but
rather of urban space, through the lex Icilia of 456 BC, which distributed the Aventine. On the
other hand, according to the tradition, the Plebeian demands for the distribution of public land
happen almost on a yearly basis, with more than ten bills rejected by the patres between 486
and 456 BC (L. Capogrossi Colognesi, La terra in Roma antica, Rome 1981, p. 6; A. Manzo,
La lex licinia sextia de modo agrorum, Naples 2001, pp. 40–45; A. Russo, ‘Tiberio Gracco e
la riforma agraria’, in G. Franciosi (ed.), La romanizzazione della Campania antica, Naples
2002, pp. 161–193; C.J. Smith, he Roman Clan. he gens from Ancient Ideology to Modern
Anthropology, Cambridge 2006, p. 240 and S.T. Roselaar, Public Land in the Roman Republic.
A Social and Economic History of Ager Publicus in Italy, 396–89 BC, Oxford and New York
2010, pp. 26–29).
17. Liv. 2.41.3: lex agraria promulgata est, nunquam deinde usque ad hanc memoriam sine maximis
motibus rerum agitata.
Revue Internationale des Droits de l’Antiquité 56 (2014)
Amunategui.indd 9 05-07-15 15:32:15
10 Carlos Felipe Amunátegui Perelló
form of a direct assignation to the poor citizens, or through the foundation of a
citizen’s colony 18. Appian describes the process in the following paragraph 19:
“Romans, while they conquered Italy’s diferent regions, took part of their
territory and established cities, or levied their own colonists to send them to the
already existent ones.”
It is interesting to corroborate the annalistic tradition with the information
that archaeology ofers. On the matter, from the 4th century BC a true explosion of
modest size settlements can be detected in Central Italy, which can be correlated
with land division and its occupation by smallholders in a process directly linked
with the leges Liciniae-Sextiae 20.
his policy of land distribution of the newly conquered land to the poor is a
key element to explain the high levels of governance and the military push that
Rome enjoyed during the Middle Republic. he city was socially cohesive, for the
common perception was that the beneits from public activity — mainly war —
were on the beneit of the common citizen, especially the poorer ones. War became
a popular activity because it implied a source of economic beneits to the citizenry
and supported socio-economic stability of the city. Military success meant a massive
input of ixed capital, an increase in the GDP and, therefore, economic growth. In
Harris’ words, Rome exported her poor to Italy and later to the provinces 21. Nearly
seventy thousand men (and their families) received land ater the Samnite wars
only 22.
4. Middle Class during Hannibal’s Wars
he beneits of war implied growth of the GDP. his growth was distributed
among the citizenry directly through land distribution, which supported the
creation of what could be called the Roman middle class. Although the concept
of Middle Class is naturally exotic to Roman ideas, following Harris 23, we could
18. It is not known for certain how much land was usually taken from the defeated enemy. It is
usually said that about a third of its territory was coniscated, although there were occasions in
which this number could increase up to two thirds (S.T. Roselaar, Public Land in the Roman
Republic. A Social and Economic History of Ager Publicus in Italy, 396–89 BC, Oxford and New
York 2010, pp. 31–37).
19. App. BC 1.1.7: Ῥωμαῖοι τὴν Ἰταλίαν πολέμῳ κατὰ μέρη χειρούμενοι γῆς μέρος ἐλάμβανον καὶ
πόλεις ἐνῴκιζον ἢ ἐς τὰς πρότερον οὔσας κληρούχους ἀπὸ σφῶν κατέλεγον.
20. N. Terrenato, ‘he essential Countryside’, in Susan E. Alcock and Robin Osborne (eds.),
Classical Archeology, Malden and Oxford 2012, pp. 147–148.
21. W.V. Harris, ‘Poverty and Destitution in the Roman Empire’, in Rome’s Imperial Economy,
Twelve Essays, Oxford and New York, Kindle Ed. 2011, l. 439.
22. T.J. Cornell, he Beginnings of Rome and Italy from the Bronze Age to the Punic Wars (c. 1000–
264 BC), London and New York 1995, p. 405.
23. W.V. Harris, ‘On the Applicability of the Concept of Class in Roman History’, in Rome’s
Imperial Economy, Twelve Essays, Oxford and New York, Kindle Ed. 2011, l. 308–315.
Amunategui.indd 10 05-07-15 15:32:15
he Decline of the Middle Class and the Fall of the Roman Republic 11
classify the Roman population according to a highly lexible criterion, which is
ultimately taken from Aristotle. We could distinguish between those who can live
depending on alien labour — from slaves or other dependent people —, those
who have enough property to secure their family’s well-being through their own
work in their land and those who are dependant workers, whether they are free or
slave 24. In this sense, those who beneit from the land distribution policy of Middle
Republican Rome become a kind of Middle Class.
Naturally, we cannot directly quantify its importance in Roman social
structure, for we do not have reliable statistics about poverty, wealth or even the
number of slaves living in Rome at any point of history. Nevertheless, we do have
one relatively trust worthy piece of information that could, to some point, help
us to do a gross estimate of its extension. hat is the number of active legions in
Rome.
he Republican army was recruited according to wealth. Only people who had
some property could be levied, while the proletarians — the have-nots —, until the
Marian reform were excluded. On the matter we have very precise information
thanks to Livy’s account 25, which might be anachronistic for Etruscan Rome, but
seems trust worthy for Middle Republican society. Livy tells us that the census
divided the army according to wealth into ive classes. hose who were under the
minimum wealth fell into the infraclassem of the proletarii and were excluded from
the army. It is likely that ater the introduction of a salary for military service in 406
BC, legions were recruited indistinctly from the ive wealthy classes 26, granted that
they were above the minimum level of proletarians.
During the Second Punic War, Rome was taken to the very limits of her military
capacity, levying some years up to twenty ive legions. Each legion, according to
Polybius 27, would have at least four thousand two hundred men, although the
igure could be higher and some legions would have up to six thousand men. If
we take a median of ive thousand men per legion, this would give us some 125
24. Following a similar criterion, Knapp speaks of the ordinary man in Rome, deining him as the
man that is socially below the senators and equestrians, but over the slave and day labourer
(R. Knapp, Invisible Romans, Cambridge 2011, p. 5).
25. Liv. 1.43. he text describes Servius Tullius’ reform, which would introduce the centuriae as the
basic units of military organization. he numbers supplemented by Livy are rather unbelievable
for monarchic Rome, for they would imply the existence of an army of almost twenty thousand
men, for a city that did not have more than ity thousand inhabitants. he most likely
hypothesis is that such description is possibly based on the data established ater the reform
of 241 BC (T.J. Cornell, he Beginnings of Rome and Italy from the Bronze Age to the Punic
Wars (c. 1000–264 BC), London and New York 1995, p. 180; C.J. Smith, he Roman Clan. he
gens from Ancient Ideology to Modern Anthropology, Cambridge 2006, p. 174; G. Forsythe, A
Critical History of Early Rome, Berkeley and Los Angeles 2006, p. 113).
26. According to Polybius, the minimum would be 400 drachmas during 216 BC. Polib. Hist.
6.19 (8).
27. Polib. Hist. 6.20.8.
Revue Internationale des Droits de l’Antiquité 56 (2014)
Amunategui.indd 11 05-07-15 15:32:15
12 Carlos Felipe Amunátegui Perelló
thousand men who could meet the minimum property standards to be part of
the army. If we consider that adult male population in Ancient cities was usually
around twenty ive per cent of the total population 28 29, this igure implies a total
population with a middle living standard of about ive hundred thousand men.
Although the total population of Italy at the time should have being around
three million inhabitants 30, Roman population shortly ater Hannibal’s war was
surveyed at 243,704 male citizens 31. If we suppose that men were about half of the
population — something not necessarily true in a period of catastrophic military
campaigns —, the total population of adult Roman citizens would be around
480 thousand people, to which we should add a number of boys and girls under
twelve and fourteen years respectively, that usually were not counted in the census.
Following Saller’s 32 population igures, with a life expectancy of about twenty ive
years, the igure would imply about a ity per cent of the total population (given
that infant mortality between 0 and 10 years would reach almost half of the births),
while if we take his upper igure of 32.5 years of life expectancy, adult population
would be about sixty per cent of the total. In short, the census igure implies a total
population between 800 and 960 Roman citizens, including children. Although the
igures we are considering are far from exact and they simply give us an order of
magnitude, they seem to tell us that between a ity two and a sixty two per cent of
Roman citizenry would have enough property to face everyday needs 33.
his is a relatively high igure for what we could call Roman Middle class. It is
true that in this igure we are deliberately ignoring the situation both of slaves and
resident foreigners, but the igure is anyhow expressive. Most Roman citizens had
28. K.A. Raaflaub, ‘he Conlict of the Orders in Archaic Rome: A Comprehensive and
Comparative Approach’, in K.A. Raaflaub (ed.), Social Struggles in Archaic Rome. New
Prespectives on the Conlict of the Orders, Oxford 2005, p. 22.
29. For a complete study using higher and lower life expectancies: W. Scheidel, ‘Demography’,
in W. Scheidel, I. Morris, and R.P. Saller (eds.), he Cambrgidge Economic History of the
Greco-Roman World, Cambridge 2007, p. 40.
30. T.J. Cornell, he Beginnings of Rome and Italy from the Bronze Age to the Punic Wars (c.
1000–264 BC), London and New York 1995, p. 180; C.J. Smith, he Roman Clan. he gens from
Ancient Ideology to Modern Anthropology, Cambridge 2006, p. 174; G. Forsythe, A Critical
History of Early Rome, Berkeley and Los Angeles 2006, p. 405; W. Scheidel, ‘Demography’,
in W. Scheidel, I. Morris, and R.P. Saller (eds.), he Cambrgidge Economic History of the
Greco-Roman World, Cambridge 2007, p. 45.
31. Liv. 35.9.21.1. On the reliability of Republican census igures: E. Lo Cascio, ‘Population and
Demographic Studies’, in J. Derose Evans (ed.), A Companion to the Archeology of the Roman
Republic, Oxford 2013, pp. 155–166.
32. R. Saller, Patriarchy, Property and Death in the Roman Family, Cambridge 1994, p. 25.
33. Our igures are slightly more optimistic than Brunt’s, that estimated the total number of assidui
in about a ity per cent of the population (P. Brunt, Italian Manpower, London 1971, pp. 64–
66), but signiicantly lower than Rosenstein’s, who estimates the total percentage of proletarii in
about a ten per cent of the population during Hannibal’s War (N. Rosenstein, Rome at War,
Chapel Hill and London 2004, pp. 185–188).
Amunategui.indd 12 05-07-15 15:32:15
he Decline of the Middle Class and the Fall of the Roman Republic 13
enough wealth to live independently, working their own land and serving in the
army during Hannibal’s war.
Regarding the elite, we have no way to quantify it, nor to measure the resources
it accumulated, but it was always a rather small group. here were no more than
three hundred senators and if we suppose a ten times larger group of equites and
add up their families, the igure could not be more than twelve hundred people,
about one per cent of the total population. To sum up, and to return to Harris’
categories, we could say that Roman population was divided into an elite that
comprehended about one per cent of the population, a Middle class that accounted
about 55–60% of population and have-nots that were between forty and forty ive
per cent of the total. hese igures sound awfully familiar and are not very diferent
to the ones a modern democracy would put forward today.
Republican political system was based on a middle class that gave Rome its
social ideal of a man that was also a soldier, a citizen and a farmer. his archetype
was the model of Republican civic life, an ideological incarnation of its virtues.
Cincinnatus, who works his small farm, who was called to save the Republic and
who returns the scarlet of dictatorship iteen days ater assuming the magistracy,
represents the Republican ideal. he common man, farmer, soldier and citizen,
assumes him as a model and can imagine himself a protector of the Republic.
Rome’s conquest of Italy was backed by a harmonious political system,
where its citizens were directly beneited by the prosperity gained. Support for
the Republican system was unanimous. With some excess, this political system
has being described as Roman democracy 34. It is beyond doubt that it was a
participatory political system, where citizenry, through the comitia and the tribunes
held power, and the common man not only had a voice in the decisions taken by
the political apparatus, but also beneited from the results. Its costs of maintenance
were extremely low, to the point that Rome did not have a police to impose order,
nor a bureaucracy to administrate the system. To call it a democracy or not is a
merely semantic problem.
5. he Decline of the Middle Classes in the Late Republic
Rome’s social order declines quickly ater Hannibal’s war. he process has
being described in several occasions and it can be related to diferent economic and
social phenomena that the military successes of Roman policy implied. From our
point of view, the most important one was the insertion of Rome in Mediterranean
long distance trade markets 35.
34. A. Guarino, ‘Forma e materia della costituzione romana’, in Studi di diritto costituzionale
romano, Naples 2008, pp. 11–26.
35. his is what Harris calls the Hellenistic-Carthaginian system, which had being operating as a
trade system from the East side to the West side of the Mediterranean basin during centuries
(W.V. Harris, ‘he Late Republic’, in W. Scheidel, I. Morris and R.P. Saller [eds.], he
Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World, Cambridge 2007, p. 513).
Revue Internationale des Droits de l’Antiquité 56 (2014)
Amunategui.indd 13 05-07-15 15:32:15
14 Carlos Felipe Amunátegui Perelló
Most of Roman smallholders were corn producers, although they usually
cultivated vines and olives too, a typical feature of the Mediterranean colotora
promiscua, which was in use in Central Italy since the seventh century BC, at
least 36. It was aimed fundamentally to self consumption, though the surpluses
were usually traded to acquire a wide range of goods that they could not produce
by themselves. Nevertheless, Roman conquests putted into market vast quantities
of superior quality grain, which entered gratis from Sicily — as a tribute — or at
very low prices, from Egypt and Africa. his immediately expelled smallholders
from grain markets, who simply could not compete. he result was the abandon
of farms by many smallholders. Even in the immediate hinterland of Rome, where
low transportation costs should help smallholders, farms were abandoned 37.
he integration of Rome into the Mediterranean markets did not only have
negative efects, but it also presented opportunities to the elite, which was in a
position to beneit with the Imperial expansion. he new markets opened vast
opportunities for agribusiness, especially for the exportation of wine, oil and
honey. Nevertheless, most farmers could not beneit from these opportunities.
Smallholders grew a crop optimized to satisfy their own corn needs. To alter
this optimum and favour a new equilibrium to get surpluses of oil or wine for
exportation would expose the farmer to famine 38. herefore, his possibilities to
adapt to this new scenario were meagre. Even more, the farmer lacked the capital
needed for the conversion 39.
he wars conducted outside Italy brought a huge inlux of liquid capital,
which came from the monetization of the riches accumulated by the Hellenistic
kings, whose vast reserves of silver were minted 40. his inlux reverted in the
beneit of the Roman elite, who could acquire through purchase or simple violence,
the farms that smallholders were in the process of abandoning. With this capital
they could create new productive units that were intended to produce surpluses
for exportation and were majorly worked by slaves. hese were the Roman villas.
Appian puts some vivid colours to the situation 41:
“he rich, hogging most of the undistributed land, with time became conident
that they were not going to be dispossessed. Partly buying through persuasive
36. G. Forsythe, A Critical History of Early Rome, Berkeley and Los Angeles 2006, p. 56.
37. N. Rosenstein, Rome at War, Chapel Hill and London 2004, p. 7.
38. K. Roberts, Origins of Business, Money and Markets, New York, Kinlde Ed. 2011, l. 2749.
39. Nevertheless, some small farms were able to do it and produced surpluses for exportation
(S.T. Roselaar, Public Land in the Roman Republic. A Social and Economic History of Ager
Publicus in Italy, 396–89 BC, Oxford and New York 2010, pp. 155–156).
40. For a detailed account see: P. Kay, Rome’s Economic Revolution, Oxford 2014, pp. 87–106).
41. App. BC 1.1.7.18: οἱ γὰρ πλούσιοι τῆσδε τῆς ἀνεμήτου γῆς τὴν πολλὴν καταλαβόντες καὶ χρόνῳ
θαρροῦντες οὔ τινα σφᾶς ἔτι ἀφαιρήσεσθαι τά τε ἀγχοῦ σφίσιν ὅσα τε ἦν ἄλλα βραχέα πενήτων,
τὰ μὲν ὠνούμενοι πειθοῖ, τὰ δὲ βίᾳ λαμβάνοντες, πεδία μακρὰ ἀντὶ χωρίων ἐγεώργουν, ὠνητοῖς
ἐς αὐτὰ γεωργοῖς καὶ ποιμέσι χρώμενοι…
Amunategui.indd 14 05-07-15 15:32:15
he Decline of the Middle Class and the Fall of the Roman Republic 15
methods, partly seizing through violence, they acquired the neighbouring
properties and all the others that belonged to humble peasants, to cultivate
latifundia…”
A bit further he adds 42:
“For these reasons the rich became maximally wealthy and the slaves abounded
in the countryside, while famine and scarce population alicted the Italian
people, decimated by poverty, taxes and military service.”
Besides the problems related to markets, war ceased to be of beneit for the
general well being of citizenry. he devastating efects of the military occupation
of Italy by Hannibal’s troops for nearly twenty years have being held responsible
for the decline of the Italian smallholder 43, although they might have not had the
importance traditionally attributed to them 44. An element that might have deeper
consequences is the development of long distance conlicts of indeinite duration.
Until Hannibal’s war, military campaigns were seasonal event that happened
inside the Italian peninsula, relatively close to the citizen-soldier’s home, who
could return to their properties in winter with the end of hostilities. War did not
interfere with agricultural labour. On the other side, the military campaigns for the
conquest of the Mediterranean basin required a permanent estrangement of the
peasant from his land to develop operations in distant war scenarios. he conquest
of Hispania implied the creation of a permanent occupation force, as also happened
later with other provinces and ended up transforming the old Mediterranean into
a new Mare Nostrum. his kind of war is incompatible with the farmer-soldier, and
it ruined a large portion of the Roman middle class. Plutarch let us an interesting
description 45:
“he dispossessed poor did not enrol in the army, nor could feed their children.
Italy was in risk of becoming completely deserted of free population and crowded
with barbarian prisoners, for they worked the lands of the wealthy, excluding the
citizens.”
Although there were various attempts to implement agrarian reforms that
could revert the disastrous results of Roman military expansion, none was able
42. App. BC 1.1.7.28: ἀπὸ δὲ τούτων οἱ μὲν δυνατοὶ πάμπαν ἐπλούτουν, καὶ τὸ τῶν θεραπόντων
γένος ἀνὰ τὴν χώραν ἐπλήθυε, τοὺς δ’ Ἰταλιώτας ὀλιγότης καὶ δυσανδρία κατελάμβανε,
τρυχομένους πενίᾳ τε καὶ ἐσφοραῖς καὶ στρατείαις.
43. P. Brunt, ‘he Army and the Land in the Roman Revolution’, Journal of Roman Studies 52
(1962), pp. 69–86 and P. Brunt, Fall of the Roman Republic and Related Essays, Oxford, 1988,
73.
44. N. Rosenstein, Rome at War, Chapel Hill and London 2004, pp. 26–62.
45. Plut. Gracch. 8.4.1–8.5.1: ἐξωσθέντες οἱ πένητες οὔτε ταῖς στρατείαις ἔτι προθύμους παρεῖχον
ἑαυτούς, ἠμέλουν τε παίδων ἀνατροφῆς, ὡς ταχὺ τὴν Ἰταλίαν ἅπασαν ὀλιγανδρίας ἐλευθέρων
αἰσθέσθαι, δεσμωτηρίων δὲ βαρβαρικῶν ἐμπεπλῆσθαι, δι› ὧν ἐγεώργουν οἱ πλούσιοι τὰ χωρία,
τοὺς πολίτας ἐξελάσαντες.
Revue Internationale des Droits de l’Antiquité 56 (2014)
Amunategui.indd 15 05-07-15 15:32:15
16 Carlos Felipe Amunátegui Perelló
to reconstruct the old class of farmers that were the backbone of the Republican
system. he necessity of reforms was evident during the second half of the second
century BC, when Gaius Laelius 46 makes such a proposal, which he eventually had
to retire, under senatorial opposition. More important were Tiberius and Gaius
Grachus reforms, which intended to rebuild the Roman smallholder class in order
to increase the availability of recruits for the legions. hey passed their laws even
against the elite’s violent answer. Anyhow, these bills were unable to revert the
decline of the smallholder. he demand for an agrarian reform was at the very
heart of every revolutionary movement and civil war that stormed the Republic
during its last century 47. Finally, when Augustus transformed the old Republic into
the Principate, Rome´s participatory government ceased to exist, as the demand
for an agrarian reform.
he decline of smallholders caused the displacement of countryside population
to Rome, which experienced a rapid increase in population, unparalleled until
the early twentieth century’s migratory movements. Rome increased its urban
population from 200–300 thousand inhabitants, during the late third century, to a
million, during the Late Republic. Rome became a city of favelas, where the poor
lived in slums over its hills, always fearing pestilence and ire.
It is almost impossible to quantify the process and to put some numbers on
the decline of Roman middle classes. Nevertheless, we can grasp the efects of such
crisis in the lack of eligible men for military service. During the late second century,
with a war burden signiicantly lower to the one experienced during Hannibal’s war
and a larger population, Rome was simply incapable of meeting the needs of the
levy. Only with Marius’ reform, which admitted for the irst time the proletarians
into the army 48, the legions could be recruited. From then on, the army became the
refuge of the poorest citizens, who saw in the legions a way out of their misery and
in the personal success of their generals, their only chance to ensure themselves
some means of subsistence.
During the second century BC Rome levied between eight and twelve
legions every year, that is to say, between forty and sixty thousand men 49. Citizen
population had grown up to almost four hundred thousand men, according to
census 50. If we repeat the calculation previously made 51 for Hannibal’s war, we
46. Plut. Gracch. 8.5.
47. P. Brunt, ‘he Army and the Land in the Roman Revolution’, Journal of Roman Studies 52
(1962), pp. 69–86.
48. Plut. Marius 9.
49. See the table included in Rosenstein (N. Rosenstein, Rome at War, Chapel Hill and London
2004, pp. 120–121).
50. he summary quotes 394,336 citizens in the census. See: Liv. Perioch. 63.
51. hat is to say, taking the maximal number of the recruited (60 thousand), the number of assidui
(that is, men over the property limit) would be about 240 thousand. If we add to the nearly 400
thousand men older than fourteen years, the missing proportion of women and children we
Amunategui.indd 16 05-07-15 15:32:16
he Decline of the Middle Class and the Fall of the Roman Republic 17
would get to the conclusion that, before Marius’ reform, Rome was not able to
stand a military burden that implied the existence of iteen and eighteen per cent
of what we earlier called middle class.
he result is eloquent. Although the numbers are not precise and are afected
by various caveat, the order of magnitude is probably correct. his would
corroborate what tradition tells us about the decline of Roman middle class,
which diminishes from covering almost two thirds of the population, to less than
a ith. he governance crisis was inevitable, and the destruction of the Republican
political system, unavoidable.
6. Conclusions
Our conclusions are, to some point, a conirmation of North’s theory. he
costs of maintenance of political system are inversely proportional to its legitimacy.
he viability of a participatory political system is directly related with the beneits
the population acquires from it. If the system tends to the creation of a large
middle class, the system will consolidate. If it the real opportunities of personal
advancement are reduced and it pauperizes the middle class, it will inevitably
implode and succumb before the ambitions of the destabilizing elements of society
that will try to replace it, either by a system that efectively distributes wealth or
by a diferent system that asserts its stability in a deeper use of coercion and social
control.
In the Roman case, it was the Principate that raised from the ashes of the
Republic, a non participatory political system, which favoured commerce and
social stability. he coercion level required to operate was higher than during the
Republic, although much lower than the later despotisms.
Nowadays, the rise of inequality in income distribution experienced in
the United States and Western Europe is rather alarming. If it deepens, the
participatory nature of their political regimes might jeopardise. he fall of what we
have called Roman middle class occurred in a relatively short period of time, less
than a century, although its efects were obvious earlier. Populism was the result of
the destruction of these middle classes. he efects of populism are not new; even
the Romans knew them well. hese are the irst symptoms of social and political
decomposition.
would arrive to a total population between 1,3 and 1,6 million citizens, depending of the life
expectancy we choose. his would give a proportion of eighteen to iteen per cent of propertied
citizens over the minimum census.
Revue Internationale des Droits de l’Antiquité 56 (2014)
Amunategui.indd 17 05-07-15 15:32:16
18 Carlos Felipe Amunátegui Perelló
Amunategui.indd 18 05-07-15 15:32:16